Population And Misanthropy

“I have no doubt that the present uprisings in Tunisia and Egypt have unsustainable population levels as their root cause,” wrote Labor backbencher Kelvin Thomson to his constituents earlier this year.
 
Not tyranny. For Thomson, the important thing to note about the crowds at Tahrir Square was not that people were angry, but that the square was very crowded.
 
Is there anything that so neatly encapsulates the misanthropy of much population scepticism?
 
His is an attitude which can marvel at nothing but the size of the teeming masses in the Arab world. No wonder at the historical nature of their revolt against dictatorship. Or speculation about the individual courage it must require. The Arab Spring is just another data point to support a belief that the world has too many people.
 
Thomson, with Dick Smith, is one of the few mainstream faces of the sustainable population movement. They blame an extraordinary array of problems on population growth – not just revolution against tyranny (which, Thomson perhaps unintentionally implied, is a bad thing) but war, famine, terrorism, over-consumption, climate change, price inflation, and the high cost of housing.
 
It’s very meta – a thread that ties together almost every single problem, real or perceived, facing the world today. Dick Smith writes in his new book:
 
Surely it is obvious that just about every problem we have is made worse by more people.
 
Not poverty, for one. The world has never been richer, and never had more people. Nor life expectancy, which has also been increasing along with population. Yes, food prices have increased modestly in recent years, but there’s little reason to believe they won’t continue their historical downwards trajectory.
 
The picture painted by the population sceptics is of a world of unmitigated catastrophe. The reality is far from that. On nearly every metric the world is getting better.
 
Even war is on a long-term decline – both in the number of conflicts and their relative deadliness.
 
As for the claims that we’re running out of resources? Fewer resources, prices for those resources go up. And as prices go up, replacements are found. Of course there is a physical limit to coal or oil. But we’ll never reach it.
 
Fear of overpopulation is just as misplaced now as it was for Thomas Malthus and Paul Ehrlich. Yet the fear sticks – the fear that this is somehow the end of the road for mankind, and the choice we now face is either to plateau or suffer.
 
So the question isn’t whether Smith and Thomson are wrong. It’s why they are.
 
Part of the explanation has to be just how deeply personal population scepticism is. Not for nothing is Smith’s book titled Dick Smith’s Population Crisis. It features photographs of his family, his childhood, and his favourite place in Australia – the tranquil, rarely-visited Coopers Creek.
 
Like his documentary Population Puzzle, the book is part argument, part lament for an Australia which has disappeared, or seems likely to. That Australia had big backyards and vegie patches and open spaces. The modern Australia, Smith claims, is at risk of becoming like Bangladesh – poor, overcrowded and environmentally degraded.
 
Of course there is no neat relationship between density and poverty. There are dense poor countries and dense rich ones. If Australia became as dense as Bangladesh we would remain rich. If Bangladesh somehow reduced its density it would likely remain poor.
 
But there is a clear relationship between population growth and the growth in living standards. Urban Bangladesh is busy because that’s where the employment opportunities are – people have left the sparse rural environment and deliberately chosen the intensity of city existence.
 
Why describe population scepticism as misanthropic?
 
Well, how else to describe those who agitate for millions of potential individuals not to exist at all – and regret the existence of millions of those who already do? Who see nothing but problems in future people?
 
The great economist Julian Simon once wrote: “What business do I have trying to help arrange it that fewer human beings will be born, each one of whom might be a Mozart or a Michelangelo or an Einstein – or simply a joy to his or her family and community, and a person who will enjoy life?”
 
As it is 2011, the population debate is inevitably wrapped up in the debate about climate change policy.
 
It will take all of the intellectual and technological ingenuity of future generations to adapt to the consequences of climate change, regardless of whether that change is caused by human activity or otherwise. Trying to reduce or stabilise population in response to climate change would be entirely counterproductive. More people have more ideas. The Thomas Edison of climate change adaptation may not have been born yet. If the sustainable population crowd have their way, he may never be born.
 
In the New York Times last week, Thomas Friedman wondered how humanity will cope with crossing the “growth/climate/natural resource/population redlines all at once”.
 
The same way we’ve always done – through human creativity.

‘Red Toryism’ Holds Little But Giggles For Local Liberals

If the Liberal Party is looking for philosophical guidance which is both coherent and electorally appealing, they won’t find it in the “Red Toryism” of Phillip Blond.
 
Blond is the founder of the UK think tank ResPublica and has been visiting Australia. He spoke to a Menzies Research Institute conference (the Liberal party’s in-house think tank) last Friday.
 
The conference is no obscure academic exercise – Blond had the ear of Tony Abbott, Andrew Robb, and Julie Bishop while he spoke.
 
A taste of Blond’s Red Tory thought was published on The Drum on last week. It’s a sort of Third Way for conservatives. Blond spends a lot of time talking about “small” – big business versus small business, big, centralised government versus small, decentralised, community-focused government. There’s a strong emphasis on social capital – the benefits of community relationships – and voluntary associations. Blond calls for a new “social capitalism”.
 
There’s much to admire about Blond’s ideas.
 
The “Big Society” – David Cameron’s grand program for the revitalization of broken Britain – was inspired by Blond’s ideas. Like Red Toryism, the Big Society was a recognition the British government had crowded out civil society organisations and undermined social capital. And that the country’s apparent social breakdown was as much caused by parliament as it was by consumer capitalism.
 
The regulatory barriers to, say, holding a street party or school fete in Britain are pernicious. Escalating health and safety requirements and council approvals have become such a burden that these essential community events are now rare.
 
The focus of Red Toryism and the Big Society on decentralisation and localism is also admirable.
 
But it’s one thing to define terms and state principles – what soars in a campaign addresses can flounder when translated to concrete public policy. Headland speeches are popular with the commentariat but have a habit of obscuring rather than illuminating. When asked how well they understand Cameron’s Big Society, two thirds of the British public say “not well”.
 
And Blond’s Red Tory philosophy is, unfortunately, a built on a pile of straw men.
 
Take, for instance, his belief that neo-liberalism, far from rejecting government regulation, necessitates it. In The Drum he argued that “if the economic actor is conceived as purely self-interested, as obeying no external codes, as living only by the internal dictate of his/her will and volition, then this actor needs regulation and tight external control.”
 
Of course, no actually-existing model of regulation conceives of individuals as “purely self-interested” who have “no external codes”. This is pure caricature.
 
Rather, the dominant model of regulation which has evolved in the 20th century seeks to manage the risk that individual actions will create undesired consequences. Free choice is not guaranteed to cause problems. But, just in case those problems arise, there’s regulation ready.
 
Governments don’t impose stringent food handling regulations because the “economic actor is conceived as purely self-interested”. They impose those regulations because politicians have determined individuals must be protected against their own lack of knowledge or ineptitude, and how those failures will impact others.
 
By attributing regulatory ideology to the “Chicago school” and neo-liberalism, Blond is blaming Britain’s over-regulation on a small government philosophy which opposes over-regulation. It’s a clever sleight of hand.
 
And it allows him to claim he wants a free market capitalism “based on trust”. This “civic economy” would apparently require almost no government, bureaucratic, or regulatory support. While his is an appealing vision – low in regulation and high in social capital – it’s based on an idiosyncratic view of why over-regulation has occurred in the first place.
 
Blond also has a cartoonish interpretation of market economics and other political ideologies. Like his belief that “In order to reclaim a civilised society, market and state should not be regarded as the ultimate goal or expression of humanity”. No-one holds those views. No-one.
 
In the end, Blond’s Red Toryism is less a revolution in political philosophy than the sort of vapid “thought-leadership” CEOs love.
 
And no surprise the public is struggling to grasp the good bits of the Big Society when its biggest philosophical backer is so confused.
 
Australian conservative politics has long taken cues from the United Kingdom. Many Liberal Party thinkers admire the progressive Tory vanguard.
 
It was a visit to Britain in 2009 which inspired Malcolm Turnbull to double down on the emissions trading scheme – Cameron’s apparently successful remaking of the Tories into environmentalists convinced the former opposition leader that was a replicable strategy in Australia.
 
Now some Liberal intellectuals are looking seriously at Blond’s Red Toryism.
 
A decade ago, many in the Labor Party were entranced by the Third Way of Tony Blair and Anthony Giddens. But as the journalist Andrew Rawnsley has said, “The Third Way was debated at earnest summits abroad and giggled to death at home.”
 
The Liberal Party should think hard before it adopts a political philosophy destined to travel the same path.

Abbott Chases Working Votes Even Menzies Forgot

There’s a certain irony when Tony Abbott conjures up the ghost of Robert Menzies for his “forgotten families”.
 
Menzies’ forgotten people were the middle class. Where the Labor Party was sectarian – the unpretentious political arm of the union movement – Menzies’ non-Labor politics would represent everybody else. (The rich and powerful, Menzies reasonably suggested, could look after themselves.)
 
But it’s obvious in 2011 Abbott has shifted his focus to the traditionally working class segments of the population – not just Howard’s aspirational battlers, but dyed-in-the-wool union members. In other words, those whose political power Menzies sought to counter.
 
Addressing the state council of the Victorian Liberal Party over the weekend, the Opposition Leader stated “Let the message go out to our country from here in Melbourne, the manufacturing heart of our country, that we must be a country that continues to make things.”
 
This of course recalls the claim by Kevin Rudd during the 2007 election campaign he didn’t want to be “Prime Minister of a country that doesn’t make things anymore.”
 
With that line, Rudd offered a sop to Labor’s union base. His Industry Minister Kim Carr spoke of thumping tables in Detroit and Beijing to get better deals for Australian manufacturers, and abandoning the doctrine of “market fundamentalism” to arrest job losses in Australian factories.
 
The desire for Australia to “make things” is evocative. Abbott obviously knows who said it first, and who the phrase is intended to appeal to.
 
The Opposition Leader claimed in his speech “there can be no first world economy without a manufacturing industry”.
 
Sure, the context was carbon pricing, which the Coalition maintains will hollow out Australian industry. Defending an industry against a tax increase is not the same as advocating it be propped up with subsidies. When the slogan “Helping Families, Protecting Jobs” – displayed prominently at state council – the Coalition is referring, in part, to the possible consequences of an emissions trading scheme on employment.
 
Australian Workers’ Union boss Paul Howes has made it abundantly clear some unions are willing to help the Coalition to stop, or at least defang, the carbon tax.
 
But there’s more going on than just the building of an anti-carbon tax alliance.
 
After all, opposition to the Government’s carbon scheme does not explain the peculiar pride in Abbott’s budget reply speech of his support for stronger anti-dumping measures which, the Opposition Leader claimed, would “protect Australian industries from way-below-cost imports”.
 
Anti-dumping laws are pure protectionism. Boosting anti-dumping laws has no economic justification. Their only rationale is psychological – so manufacturers feel like they have a legal defence against cheap foreign products.
 
The Productivity Commission has found anti-dumping laws benefit a small number of industrial firms at the expense of all consumers.
 
And the only other major group which supports the extension of anti-dumping laws is the Australian Workers’ Union. The union’s ‘Don’t Dump on Australia’ campaign makes them unlikely allies with the Coalition. The AWU is being consistent. The Coalition is being opportunistic.
 
Nobody imagines Tony Abbott is a doctrinaire free marketeer.
 
The Coalition’s ‘Action Contract’, released in June last year, was in many ways typically Liberal – full of Menziesian references to small businesses and schools.
 
But the Action Contract was produced at a time when the Labor government was not so hopeless. It still seemed possible in 2010 the ALP might retain many of those who gave it victory in 2007. A year later it’s clear the ALP has lost the progressive vote to the Greens, and (with the carbon price) its industrial support looks shaky.
 
Hence Abbott sees opportunity for the Coalition. His regime of factory tours and shift in rhetoric suggest that if an election was held today, the Action Contract could have a substantially different hue. The Opposition Leader appears to believe the Coalition could win the hearts of Labor’s industrial left in the very near future.
 
But you can’t be everything to everyone.
 
As Phillip Coorey pointed out in Monday’s Sydney Morning Herald, the Coalition’s approach has also meant industrial relations – one of the few areas where Abbott personally supports serious market-orientated reform – has been put even further back on the shelf.
 
It would not do to alienate the AWU by recalling the ghost of WorkChoices when you’re working so well together.
 
This seems to be what Nick Minchin was getting at when he distinguished last week between populism and policy principle.
 
Much has been made of the rootlessness of the contemporary Labor Party. And the Coalition is reshaping its image in response to problems in the federal ALP.
 
But by chasing the votes of the industrial left, the Coalition risks abandoning its own base, and the affinity to economic liberalism which makes it distinctive.

Backwoods Policy Making

Released on the Friday after the federal budget, the Government’s Sustainable Population Strategy is for the most part just 88 pages of promotional guff and colour photos.

But it isn’t entirely meaningless.

Seemingly minor policies in the population strategy suggest a larger plan by federal and state governments to shift population growth and employment away from cities and to the regions.

You’ve probably heard about the migration changes already. As Julia Gillard said, “I don’t want the first port of call for migrants to our country to always be the growing suburbs of Sydney and Melbourne”. That’s the payoff of the 2010 election’s small Australia rhetoric. Skilled immigrants will be directed towards regions rather than urban areas.

But it’s not only about migrants – governments want existing urban residents to move to the regions too. The Promoting Regional Living Program funds rural areas to promote themselves to city dwellers.

And on top of these federal initiatives are the existing state incentives for people to move away from the big smoke. A number of states – Victoria and Queensland, for example – boost their first home owners grant if purchasers buy away from urban areas.

You can understand why governments want to take pressure off city growth. Trains and trams seem packed. Infrastructure has not kept up with demand – or, if it has, no voters seem to believe it.

Yet policy makers shouldn’t forget the basic reasons many people want to live and work in dense urban areas when they haven’t been induced to do otherwise.

The Harvard economist Edward Glaeser has described the city as humanity’s “greatest invention”. Policies which try to divert growth away from cities – shift activity and population away from where they would otherwise prefer to go – could create more problems than they solve.

After all, an urban population is a richer population. In his new book, Triumph of the City: How Our Greatest Invention Makes Us Richer, Smarter, Greener, Healthier, and Happier, Glaeser describes the “near-perfect correlation” between urbanisation and prosperity.

City dwellers aren’t only richer – they’re happier too. The more urban a nation, the higher that nation’s reported happiness, even after you factor in the happiness-boosting effect of income and education.

Successful cities, Glaeser uncontroversially says, are those which attract smart and creative people, and allow those people to interact in close proximity to each other.

That interaction sparks aggregate economic growth and individual economic opportunity for creative and non-creative alike.

And, of course, cities have amenities. It’s easier to provide services to dense communities, and provide a greater array of those services.

None of these benefits of city living are novel to anyone, of course. They’re why cities exist in the first place.

Tree and sea changes may be appealing, but regional and remote areas offer fewer ways to earn money – and fewer ways to spend it. A report in the Sunday Age in 2009 found a substantial proportion of people moving to quieter parts of the country regretted it – 90 per cent planned to leave within the next five years.

As one academic said at the time, “People bought the dream about the idealistic country life, then they moved there and were confronted by the reality: poor health care, poor road quality, fewer work opportunities, expensive food, lack of entertainment, obesity, lack of ethnic diversity, difficulty making friends, conservatism and narrow-mindedness. They expected to find an enjoyable life with less work and less traffic. But they found a lack of stability, lower pay and longer commutes.”

We’re all familiar with the cliché that small towns have a sense of community. But cities have networks of communities. Not only are there are more people in a city with whom relationships can be formed, but the greater diversity of interests allows niche communities to develop.

Each to their own, obviously.

But the well-known advantages of urban living should make you wonder about the wisdom of deliberately encouraging people to move away.

Do we really want migrants to settle outside the capital cities, where formal and informal support networks are smaller or absent? Migrants choose cities for the same reason everybody else does – services, employment, and social opportunity.

And do we really want to be subsidising first home buyers – people early in their career and family life – to move to areas with more limited prospects for personal and job development?

Sure, if people choose to move away from cities and to regional areas, that’s their business. But it’s a problem if government policy deliberately induces people to do so – to buy houses and find their feet in areas which, all else being equal, have fewer opportunities, fewer essential services and offer a potentially lower standard of living.

Public policy should not favour cities, certainly. But neither should it encourage people to leave them.

Middle Class Welfare: Not Happy Julia

Perhaps families earning $150,000 a year are “rich”. Perhaps they’re not.
 
But it’s intuitively obvious they shouldn’t receive welfare.
 
That’s because, deep down, we’re all small-l liberals. Welfare should be a safety net, not a web in which everybody is tangled.
 
The Gillard government’s reductions in family payments announced as part of last week’s federal budget are modest but welcome.
 
The income test on some payments will be frozen until 2014, as will the size of payments. Inflation will slowly erode eligibility and value. The teacup storm about cost of living pressures and what constitutes rich was inevitable.
 
But the thing is, direct welfare going to middle income earners in Australia is actually quite low, at least compared to the rest of the world. Our benefits are relatively well means-tested. The Rudd and Gillard governments have made them even more so – a much needed corrective to the Howard years.
 
Commentators rightly condemn the non-means tested benefits which remain. The tax-welfare churn is extremely inefficient.
 
But subsidising the middle class isn’t a strange perversion of the welfare state. It’s a key characteristic.
 
For decades we’ve been told we should emulate the big social democratic welfare states – it’d be the only progressive thing to do. Yet their full cradle-to-grave social support offers far more for middle earners than Australia does.
 
The prototypical Scandinavian welfare models were built on the concept of universalism. Everybody gets something. Their political support relies on that universalism. Middle income earners approve of those welfare states because they’re the beneficiaries.
 
Indeed, the Swedish economist Andreas Bergh has argued that redistribution of income from rich to poor is a relatively minor feature of the Scandinavian model – the whole system is structured to service the comfortable middle.
 
So if it is intuitively obvious to Australians that the middle class shouldn’t receive income support, that’s because we find the social democratic model of the welfare state objectionable.
 
The Australian conception of the proper role of welfare is a liberal one. Income support should be only given to those who need it – to those whose only alternative to Centrelink is poverty. Not to those who, facing money pressures, could reduce consumption or live in a smaller house or trade in a new car.
 
Even mainstream Australian social democrats argue against the social democratic model of the welfare state.
 
In the Weekend Australian, Tim Soutphommasane (of the progressive think tank Per Capita) said “Any fair and efficient system of welfare … should be guided by a principle of need.”
 
The past decade and a half has seen government extend its generosity to middle income earners, breaking the liberal compact.
 
Unfortunately the Gillard government hasn’t pitched its temporary freeze on family payments as a principled shift in welfare policy. In fact, quite the opposite: it has stubbornly insisted families deserve whatever they can get.
 
As Wayne Swan said late last month: “Australians who work hard, who get up every day, send their kids to school, come home, cook the tea, get up and do it again, whether they’re running a small business or working for wages, are deserving of some support for their children when they’re performing that vital role of bringing up the next generation of young Australians.”
 
This makes welfare less about need, and more like a reward given by the government for being responsible and virtuous. So it’s no surprise that there’s outcry when the government reduces that reward. After all, families haven’t stopped working hard – why is the government suddenly being so miserly?
 
The Howard government wrapped its middle income support in different rhetoric. For John Howard, middle class welfare was a deliberate program to achieve a specific social goal. Each side favours income support for “working families”, it’s just that they put the emphasis on different words.
 
Speaking to the conservative think tank the American Enterprise Institute after he left office, the former Prime Minister argued that:
 
“We should maintain a cultural bias in favour of traditional families … The taxation system should generously recognise the cost of raising children. This is not middle class welfare. It is merely a taxation system with some semblance of social vision.”
 
For Labor, middle class welfare is a reward. For the Coalition, it’s an incentive.
 
Howard was a conservative social democrat. Sure, sometimes he looked like a proponent of small government. More often (much more often) he did not.
 
The Liberal Prime Minister had a distinct pro-family, pro-procreation philosophy which, in his view, supported the expansion of family payments. For Howard, income testing those payments would be contrary to the purpose of the policy, and at odds with the philosophy. You might not agree with that philosophy of government – free marketeers shouldn’t, and didn’t – but it was a coherent one, and one which he often articulated.
 
By contrast, Labor appears to share Howard’s policy preferences, yet it cannot explain why.
 
Nevertheless, the end result of both approaches has been the development of a middle class entitlement culture – a culture that’s long been endemic in larger universal welfare states, and now seems to be growing in Australia.

Ignoring The Deficit: Disappointingly Predictable

Is there any less edifying event in Australian politics than The Budget?

Each year the Treasurer offers a seemingly arbitrary smattering of policy adjustments and spending programs.

This year the Family Tax Benefit A has been extended. Small businesses will be able to write-off $5,000 of new car costs. Free set top boxes for pensioners. Trades apprentices get a $1,700 bonus on completion. Former prisoners of war get another $500 a fortnight.

Check them off: families, small businesses, pensioners, apprentices, Our Boys.

Some of these have obvious merit, some obviously not.

In his mind, Wayne Swan is the government’s hard man. But giveaways do not bring to mind the toughness he wants to project.

In 2010, a tough and “no frills” budget included a 50 per cent tax discount for the first $1,000 of interest earned on savings. The low income tax offset was increased to $1,500. Government superannuation top ups for people earning $37,000 or less. Small business write-offs for assets worth less than $5,000. More money for veterans. More money for renewable energy, skills, and rail. More money for elite sport.

No frills there.

In 2009, another “tough budget”: Tax concessions on super contribution reduced from $50,000 to $25,000 a year. The small business tax break on assets increased 50 per cent. First home grants boosted for another six months. Pension payment increases. Supplements for carer payment recipients. More money for pretty much everything.

In 2008, a “tough but fair budget”… anyway, you get it.

It’s a bit rich to describe a budget as tough if it includes free electronics.

Nevertheless, the budget process itself encourages uncoordinated and haphazard policymaking.

After all, the budget is not just an annual restatement of the government’s financial health. It is the centre of the policy process. It is clearly unsuited for this role. The budget is not a great frame in which to develop public policy.

Government departments submit ambit claims, ministers push hard for programs which could demonstrate they’ve achieved something, and everything gets filtered through a political mesh, packaged into “deliverables” and rolled out in leaks.

Then the Treasurer tries to teeter between generosity and hardheadedness, prepare a speech, and try to place himself at the symbolic heart of the government.

Any substantial policy reform gets quickly subsumed into the budget spectacle – one thing must be offset by another, and spending reductions become only justifications for further spending in other areas. The only purpose of savings is for more spending.

Take the government’s dignity-of-work welfare changes, which are as much about savings as they are about reform.

As Alan Kohler pointed out on Tuesday night, $21.7 billion worth of savings in this budget was matched with $18.9 billion in new spending. Cuts made while spending added; programs expanded while other programs reduced. That’s policy churn – the sort of fiddling which makes the tax code blossom and keeps accountants in business.

At its best the budget process results in incremental approaches to policy issues. At its worst, a ballooning of under-resourced and utterly ineffective programs. $34 million dollars to help manufacturers supply resource projects? This is surely too low a figure to achieve its ambitious goal, yet too high to be dismissed as trivial.

No wonder budgets marketed as tough come off as indecisive.

The pressures of budget time are not conducive to coherent policy. But on the other side, the budget spectacle – the May policy dump – has made it hard to strongly confront fiscal problems when they arise.

2011-12 is yet another budget in the expanding shadow of the global financial crisis. The decisions made by Kevin Rudd, Wayne Swan, Lindsay Tanner, and Ken Henry in a few critical months still dominate the fiscal landscape. (Julia Gillard may have been in the famous “kitchen cabinet”, but according to Lenore Taylor and David Uren in Shitstorm, she was in the outer kitchen cabinet.)

Three out of those four – Rudd, Henry, and Tanner – have now left the economic policy stage. Swan is now the sole custodian of the government’s crisis legacy, and the man who has to live with its consequences.

The Treasurer has not seriously attempted to tackle the stubbornly growing budget imbalance which resulted from his decisions nearly three years ago. Instead, he’s relied on Treasury forecasts about a possible revenue surge in the future. That surge keeps being postponed while the target to return to surplus gets closer and closer.

The government is playing chicken with the economy, hoping revenue will catch spending before the self-imposed 2013 wall.

It may – perhaps Treasury’s projections are right this time – but would you really want to bet on it?

Our economy faces the world. What happens in China, or the United States, or Europe, makes a big difference to our terms of trade, our dollar, and ultimately the government’s revenue. And the last few years have been some of the most volatile in the global economy in the last few decades.

In this environment, Wayne Swan cannot be comfortable gambling his reputation on the reliability of Treasury projections.

We could shout ourselves hoarse asking Swan to put those projections aside and to take positive measures to reduce the deficit. The Treasurer might, if he wanted to, cut spending deep and hard – a good idea whether the budget is in the red or the black. But there’s no real demand for an Australian age of bureaucratic austerity.

So the government’s reluctance to face its deficit is predictable, if disappointing.

Without the support of his crisis co-conspirators, Swan appears to be hoping the budget will just fix itself.

The Nanny State Is Coming…For Your Democratic Soul

Is saying “nanny state” just a cheap slur?

The term was coined in The Spectator in 1965 and clearly bears the marks of that publication and that era.

I have in my collection half a dozen academic papers published in public health journals decrying its use: “The nanny state fallacy”; “No need for nanny”; “Nanny or Steward?” “Medical police and the nanny state: Public health or private autonomy?” and so on.

One, co-written by a prominent member of the Rudd government’s Preventative Health Taskforce, Mike Daube, compares “nanny state” to the phrase “health Nazi”. Daube and his colleagues argue the latter is needlessly offensive and the former is “an easy phrase in the same tradition”.

Daube’s artless comparison reminds us that one can protest too much. The problem some in the public health community have with the nanny state appellation isn’t that it’s unfair. It’s that it resonates with the public.

And we rely on “nanny state” because it describes something very specific – an observable and concrete change in the way government relates to individuals. It has no obvious or elegant alternative.

Where more “traditional” regulatory interventions try to protect individuals against the adverse consequences of the decisions of others, the nanny state primarily seeks to protect individuals from themselves. As with all public policy, supporters deploy a wide variety of justifications, but this is what makes nanny unique.

And the attitude which underpins such paternalistic policy has implications far beyond alcohol and fast food. It is, in a very real way, profoundly undemocratic.

If we can’t trust people to choose their poison, then how can we trust them with a vote?

That question may sound glib. But democratic legitimacy rests on a positive belief that while not all citizens may be equally intelligent or informed, they are equally sovereign, and as a consequence have the right to have a say about the country’s future. In their own small way.

The systematic chipping away by nanny state activists of these assumptions – that people should be assumed to be competent to make such portentous choices themselves – presents more of a challenge to democratic legitimacy than the public health community may recognise.

Nobody is suggesting a cadre of experts should guide citizens to make the correct political choices. They never will. (The public health community would no doubt be horrified at the thought.) But it is just as hard to see not, given this paternalist philosophical stance.

After all, we have undermined the notion of individual responsibility to such a degree that some government advisors no longer even trust people to, say, manage their own food serving size (the Preventative Health Taskforce suggested regulators standardise portions in restaurants).

Basic notions of political equality should compel us to leave those food portion decisions in the hands of individuals, not state-appointed experts. We cannot pretend to have a legitimate democracy if the government operates under a presumption that voters are idiots.

So dismissing individual responsibility has consequences. Once you’ve accepted that the government should not treat people as autonomous, all sorts of authoritarian policy results.

The increasing centrality of income management for welfare recipients is driven by the same philosophy. To support nanny regulations yet oppose income management is incoherent.

That’s a hypocrisy found on the left. On the right, drug-warriors against the nanny state are just as contradictory.

This is why the strongest objections to nanny interventions have always been philosophical, not practical or economic. The nanny state is a radical reworking of the relationship between individual and state.

Certainly, some nanny interventions have been going on for a long time, and, in retrospect, few find them are objectionable.  Seatbelt laws protect people from the consequences of their own decisions and potentially the behaviour of others.

The difference is of degree, not kind. But there is a difference nonetheless.

Where we can isolate one or two regulations of the past with similar purpose, the nanny state of the 21st century is expansive and insatiable. It’s a volume thing.

The Preventative Health Taskforce proposed 122 separate recommendations to clamp down on alcohol, tobacco, and weight-gain. It recommended seven entirely new bureaucracies be set up. It suggested twenty-six new laws and regulations.

Some critics have begun to describe paternalist interventions as indicative of a “bully state” mentality; a graduation from nudging to shoving. While this is true for some new and proposed regulations, it’s not clear that, say, imposing new, simplified food labeling laws is really bullying.

The Nobel-winning economist James Buchanan tried to rename the nanny state “parental socialism”. Buchanan’s alternative has an appeal, but its second word is louder than the first. And nanny is the better metaphor. In a democratic system, government is the hired help who we delegate to perform collective tasks – not actually our progenitors or superiors.

We could invent other phrases.

Public health activists are clearly frustrated by the nanny state critique. So they should be. They do not understand how substantial a challenge their ideas are to the philosophical assumptions which underpin liberal democracy.

Morality And Humanity In The Gambling Debate

Opposition to gambling has always been somewhat aesthetic and moralistic. The character of that moralising has, however, changed over time.

During the Middle Ages, betting was seen as unproductive and idle. Only knights, clergymen, and monarchs had sufficiently good character to be allowed to play dice for money.

A few hundred years later, Reformation era moralists saw gambling as sin. It was blasphemous to ask God to decide such trivial matters as dice throws.

Their Enlightenment descendants imagined gambling to be irrational; contrary to the spirit of the age of reason. The 19th century saw it as a social disorder; disruptive, inefficient, and, as a consequence, borderline criminal.

Anti-gambling activists of the early 20th century focused on class. The lower and upper orders played different games. Predictably and unfairly, working-class gambling was suppressed, and upper-class gambling left alone.

Today, the vast bulk of anti-gambling opinion has a medical hue. We now see gambling mostly through the prism of illness and addiction.

Mental health concerns are genuine and serious and do not deserve to be dismissed out of hand – regardless of whether we think the Government should step in to manage or override people’s choices.

But the aesthetic and moralistic critique of gambling has not disappeared.

Certainly it’s obvious that opposition to, for instance, poker machines, is not solely based on data revealing the relative incidence of problem gambling occurring on the pokies compared to other games.

A part of that opposition (we can disagree how big a part) is undeniably grounded on how the pokies look ‘sad’. Playing is solitary. Players appear joyless. A poker machine seems to be a mechanised and computerised tool of corporate manipulation; a metaphor of consumer capitalism made real. (‘People cannot seriously enjoy pokies, can they?’)

These impressions colour the debate over poker machine regulation.

Nick Xenophon’s weekend statements suggest much of the political push against the pokies is motivated not by a belief that the pokies are uniquely dangerous, but by a distaste for gambling in general.

The South Australian Senator is drafting a bill to crack down on online betting. And he’s upset about the very existence of sports wagers. In comments to The Age on Saturday, he said he wants to “ban commentators referring to the odds”, ban “odds being broadcast” and impose “restrictions on the maximum bets being able to be played”.

Xenophon would also like advertising of online gambling sites to be banned, having argued in the past gambling advertising should be regulated as heavily as tobacco advertising – in other words, regulated out of existence.

The reasons Xenophon offers for such restrictions are many and familiar. He argues gambling poses dangers to sport itself – match-fixing is inevitable in a world where sports betting is widespread.

‘Children – think of the children!’ could be normalised to gambling. This is left unexplored, but is presumably undesirable; the implicit argument being that sports betting, while not necessarily harmful itself, is a gateway drug to the RSL.

Then, of course, the aesthetic argument: “It’s a shame for the great game of cricket that it’s been reduced to just another event to have a punt on,” Xenophon said in 2008.

Whether gambling enhances “the great game” or undermines it, preserving the enjoyableness of sporting events should not be a central concern of parliament, let alone the Commonwealth Parliament.

As the social scientist Gerda Reith argued in her 1999 book The Age of Chance: Gambling in Western Culture, gambling is endemic, historically and in the modern world. And, as a consequence, has developed great cultural significance.

Through gambling, people engage both the mathematical concept of probability, and the metaphysical concept of chance. It’s a way to make light of risk; to tame uncertainty.

In other words, gambling is part of human nature.

Given gambling’s cultural centrality, it’s not clear why the Government should try to wall it off; to regulate gambling into an isolated and denigrated corner of the Australian consciousness.

Rather than treating gambling as alien and dangerous and not fit for children, why not treat it as a normal part of being and encourage it to be enjoyed responsibly?

Gambling is, after all, just a game.

Bookmakers are running odds on nearly every facet of the royal wedding: the first dance, the colour of the bride’s dress, the colour of Victoria Beckham’s dress, whether Prince Phillip will fall asleep during the ceremony, whether chicken tikka masala will be the main course, and whether Prince Harry will drop the ring and be too drunk to finish his speech (25-1, as of a few days ago). And, unsurprisingly, on the chances of divorce.

These bets do not detract from the wedding, which will be as painful as it would be in a world without wagers.

They do, however, make a game out of it – transforming the public from spectators to participants.

For moralist opponents of gambling like Nick Xenophon, such engagement only conjures up images of ruin.

But there is no need to be that pessimistic. The desire to play games of chance is a part of the human condition. Archaeologists have discovered four sided sticks – proto-dice – dating to 6000BC. In 2011, let’s try not be so scared of it.

Why Bad Policy Can Be Good Politics

Why would the Gillard government want to cut an unambiguously popular area of government spending – medical research? Because, perversely, it may be good politics.
The Prime Minister has promised to bring the budget back into surplus as quickly as possible. There is considerable political pressure on her to do so, and (as far as the budget deficit accords with a general perception of her government as hopelessly wasteful) considerable public pressure as well.
So the government needs to talk about tough choices. And nothing demonstrates toughness than cutting medical research.
The government is apparently considering slicing $400 million off the National Health and Medical Research Council. The Council looks at things like cancer treatment, trauma psychology, child allergies, cot-death, and genetic heart defects. It’s a pretty sympathetic Commonwealth body.
So if the rumours are true, the government is playing a familiar game. When cutting against your wishes, cut in the most painful place. Government bureaucracies do this all the time. Bureaucrats have a powerful incentive to make budget cuts hard for their political masters.
When in 2008 the Rudd government insisted the Australian Bureau of Statistics take a haircut of $20 million, the ABS’s immediate response was slice into two of its most necessary statistical functions – retail sales data and labour force numbers. The ABS couldn’t have picked more painful and sensitive things. If those figures aren’t reliable, then, for instance, the Reserve Bank would struggle to do its job at all.
Next the public sector union claimed that the census would be next on the chopping block; that the budget reductions meant the 2011 census would have to be exactly the same as the 2006 census, instead of being updated. Welfare agencies cut things like taxi trips for children with disabilities. Education departments close schools, instead of reducing the blossoming ranks of administrators, the paper-shufflers, and the lavish consultancies to friendly specialists in academia. School closures do not play well in the press.
In 2009, Hawaii’s education department was told to make savings. Instead of cutting jobs, it cancelled school on Fridays. Similarly, Julia Gillard and Wayne Swan have an incentive to make deficit reduction look as tough as possible.
To paraphrase American journalist and satirist HL Mencken, if the public wants cuts in government spending, they’re going to get them good and hard. And the louder the research community complains, the tougher the government looks.
The government has been accused of wasteful spending at every opportunity. Tony Abbott has made “the BER” and “pink batts” into all-purpose symbols of fiscal recklessness. So Julia Gillard probably welcomes the thought of having taxpayer-funded researchers rally across the country to protest her austerity measures.
There’s a very good chance the medical research cuts won’t be made. If the government follows this well-thumbed script, it will back down – “saving” research while simultaneously demonstrating an eagerness to make tough budget calls.
Still, the research cuts put Tony Abbott in a spot. The opposition leader prides himself on clarity of message. When opposing a government that cannot shake the impression of hopelessness, simplicity works. Cutting the debt was point one of the Coalition’s “Action Contract” in June last year. Ending the waste was point two.
Yet Abbott gets into trouble when he tries to fill in the detail of what, specifically, he would like to cut to bring the budget back to surplus Every government program has a vocal constituency certain that their funding is the difference between refined, advanced civilisation and a brutish Hobbesian state of nature.
Now he’s found himself opposing a reduction in government expenditure. The Coalition’s health spokesman, Peter Dutton, said over the weekend that “The Coalition is going to the barricades over this one. We won’t stand for hundreds of millions being ripped from research.” It muddies the Coalition’s otherwise simple and clear message about reducing spending – a side-effect which wouldn’t disappoint the government at all.
Of course, just because strategic budget cuts might be good politics don’t mean they’re good policy. The medical research community is quite upset. Yet its reaction does raise the question of whether there is such thing as an optimal amount of funds directed towards medical research.
Is all medical research spending the most efficient research spending? Or can funds only ever increase? Do we have the right mix of private and public? Are the incentives for private firms to develop new treatments the best they can be?
Or is it uncouth to ever ask such impertinent questions? Perhaps so.
Yet our deep reluctance to ask them is why these sorts of cuts are more politically clever than they first appear. The government wants to look tough on spending. And nothing’s tougher than cutting the development of new cancer treatments.

Learning From Public Policy Mistakes Of The GFC

In the Financial Times at the end of March, the former Federal Reserve Chairman Alan Greenspan wrote “With notably rare exceptions (2008, for example), the global ‘invisible hand’ has created relatively stable exchange rates, interest rates, prices, and wage rates”.

That statement is mundanely true. But as it came from Greenspan, it was not well received.

Left-leaning blogs have had great fun: “With notably rare exceptions, the levees protecting New Orleans have held fast in the face of major hurricanes”.

The Nobel winning economist-turned-polemicist Paul Krugman wrote he “didn’t know quite how to respond”.

The Global Financial Crisis still looms large.

Our understanding of the crisis will shape debate about the role of government and the fragility or robustness of markets for decades.

So it’s important to get it right – to pinpoint exactly what went wrong in the US housing market and what caused it. The particulars are important.

Those particulars make it hard to shove the crisis into a morality play of deregulation and rampant greed.

We know a lot more about the crisis than we did in 2008 and 2009.

The US government’s Financial Crisis Inquiry Commission reported this January. While its majority report largely fails to interrogate the structural origin of the housing bubble, a dissenting report released as an appendix is much more interesting.

Written by Peter Wallison of the American Enterprise Institute, the dissent rigorously documents the deliberate erosion of lending standards by successive American administrations.

As Wallison writes, in the early 1990s lending standards were seen as a barrier to home ownership for low and middle-income families.

The solution was the Housing and Community Development Act of 1992, which intended to give those families better access to mortgage credit through the government-sponsored enterprises Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac.

Fannie and Freddie had been, until then, conservative and relatively benign, trading mortgages on the secondary market since the Great Depression. But with the 1992 Act they now had a new mandate, a social mission.

Over the next 15 years the Government ratcheted up the affordable housing goals.

The result of these goals was spectacular.

By 2008, “non-traditional” mortgages (loans made to those with blemished credit, or lacking documentation, or with negligible down-payment) made up a massive 58 per cent of the total US mortgage market.

And US government entities – primarily Fannie and Freddie – were either directly holding or guaranteeing 71 per cent of those non-traditional loans.

This was a successful program, under its own terms. It boosted homeownership rates substantially. But the housing bubble it created eventually burst.

The received wisdom on this boom in non-traditional mortgages has focused on fraud by lenders, the naivety of borrowers, and the greed of investment bankers who packaged them into complex and inscrutable investments.

This tale has been reinforced by bookstores full of hastily-written financial crisis porn, rich with anecdotes about fast-living financiers and lazy lenders.

Yet in a market engorged by government affordable-housing goals, these bankers no more epitomise the ‘invisible hand’ than the US Congress does.

So three years after the crisis, the policies which caused the housing bubble are starting to get their due recognition.

As are the mistakes made in 2008, while the bubble was collapsing.

If the erosion of lending standards was the long-term cause of the crisis, then the actions of the US government in 2008 was the short-term one – badly deepening the crash and impeding the recovery.

Since the 1980s, the US government had slowly built an expectation it would bailout big firms if they got into trouble. This expectation was never explicit. You wouldn’t want to bet the company on it. But it was there.

Still, the bailout of the investment bank Bear Sterns in March 2008 came as a surprise. Sure, Bear Sterns was deeply involved in non-traditional mortgages, but it was only a mid-sized firm. If Bear Sterns was “too big to fail”, so were dozens of others.

When the Federal Reserve stepped in to save Bear Sterns, it was massively expanding the government’s implied support net.

In retrospect, many participants have blamed the failure to bailout Lehman Brothers in September for the crash. And it is true that the market only truly sunk after it became clear Lehman would be left to fail, and investors realised government help was not guaranteed.

But Lehman’s actions in the week after the Bear Sterns bailout reveal the real problem in 2008.

Bear Stern’s near collapse in March should have inspired all participants to stop and reassess the quality of the mortgage-backed securities they were holding.

Instead, Lehman doubled-down, packaging all their riskiest assets into a special fund with one purpose – as collateral to borrow money from the Federal Reserve. In other words, instead of limiting their risk, they increased it.

For Lehman and other firms, maximising the chances for a bailout became the main game. Not cleaning balance sheets and taking a financial hit. As a former director of the Federal Reserve Bank, Vince Reinhart, has argued, the question becomes less “how do we get out of this mess?” and more “how much money will the government pony up first?”

Expectations changed again in September with Lehman’s collapse. The US economy froze. The global panic began. Governments initiated an unprecedented series of interventions and stimulus packages.

And the name of the Lehman Brothers fund specifically designed to take advantage of Federal Reserve largesse and the banking sector’s new claim on taxpayer dollars?

The “Freedom” fund.

Memory of the Great Depression shaped economic policy in the second half of the 20th century. The Great Recession will shape the next 50 years.

So let’s not let our understanding of its causes slip into a vague haze of myth and cliché. The crisis was caused not by greed, or deregulation, or neo-liberalism. It was caused by a web of public policy mistakes – if well-intentioned ones – and their unintended consequences.