Things Get Messy When Popularity Trumps Policy

Hard to believe it, but the 2015 budget was delivered just three weeks ago.

Already the Abbott Government seems eager to move on.

Last week Tony Abbott announced the creation of a terror tsar, a new minister for counterterrorism, and a policy to strip Australian citizenship from dual nationals suspected of terrorist activities.

National security is important. And the Government has been telegraphing the citizenship changes for months. But the question is: why now? Why so soon?

The budget was delivered on Tuesday, May 12. National security week was launched on Monday, May 25. That’s 13 days. Really just 12, if you factor in the budget lockup and newspaper print deadlines.

This quick hop from economics to security is indicative of a broader problem with the Abbott Government’s populist push. It knows it doesn’t want to be unpopular. But it’s not sure what it wants to be popular about.

The 2015 budget is nothing like the political catastrophe that the 2014 budget was. If anything it has been well received. Everybody likes the accelerated depreciation changes for small business. The fiscal reckoning has been postponed, and nobody but sticklers, obsessives and economists could object to that.

So Labor has struggled to gain traction against the budget. That “fairness” thing, so potent last year, looks a bit sad when thrown at a budget specifically designed to avoid such attacks. It’s been widely observed that Abbott is doing better in part because Shorten looks played out.

National security week didn’t last long. The process was derailed by Joe Hockey’s Monday night Q&A blurt that he was open to exempting tampons from the GST, Bill Shorten’s announcement that he was going to introduce a gay marriage bill on Tuesday night, then the publication of incredibly detailed leaks out of cabinet about the citizenship stripping proposal.

Whatever momentum national security was to provide the Government was well and truly stalled by mid-week.

The Government has haplessly tried to put the gay marriage issue back in the box by saying that it is focused on getting the budget through Parliament. Marriage can wait. There are small business tax concessions to be passed. Yet this argument would be more convincing if the Government hadn’t already moved its attention from the budget to national security.

It’s very messy.

One of the conceits that the political class have is that they can host “public conversations” about the issues that matter to them; that the tone and topic of debate in the public sphere can be directed by the Prime Minister’s Office.

Sometimes this does work, admittedly. Hockey did manage to genuinely spark a discussion about tax earlier this year with the release of the tax discussion paper. The discussion took a turn the Government was not necessarily pleased about. Every special interest group used the space to air their proposals for new taxes. Still, at least everybody was on-topic. More often the public isn’t interested in talking about what PMO is.

Very quickly the national security issue became less about the threat of terror and more about divisions within cabinet and shadows of the leadership question. The imminent legalisation of gay marriage had more public “cut through” than the creation of a terror tsar. Perhaps even more than it would have, had the Government been less reluctant to talk about Shorten’s proposal. Nothing is more interesting than division in the ranks.

Now the Government wants to have a “national conversation” about the meaning of citizenship in an age of terror. This does not promise to be a particularly enlightening conversation. Nor a fruitful one, as it looks to simply expose the wavering support within the Government and its backbench for the rule of law.

Last week wasn’t just a case study in how policy debate can go off the rails, but a more significant indication of the long term importance of the 2015 budget.

Budgets usually loom large in the Australian political calendar, but the 2014 budget was a vortex sucking in everything around it. This year’s budget is a bit of a return to form. Parliament and the public are much calmer.

Yet a forgettable budget is hardly what the times demand.

The Australian Bureau of Statistics reported that capital investment in Australia fell in the March quarter by the largest amount since the Global Financial Crisis.

If this is a harbinger of things to come, Tony’s Tradies are going to need more than accelerated depreciation to ride out the storm.

Political historians will remember the 2014 budget for the heartache it gave the Government. But economic historians will remember this year’s budget for having reconciled the country to decades of debt and deficit.

Abbott’s eagerness to move on from economics to security is unfortunately more revealing about the future direction of this Government than anything his Treasurer released last month.

Magna Carta: The tax revolt that gave us liberty

With John Roskam, Institute of Public Affairs, 2015

‘Our liberty, democracy, and human rights are all in some way related to what was inscribed on parchment at Runnymede in June 1215’

The Magna Carta is a founding document of individual liberty, rule of law, and parliamentary democracy. In this accessible and engaging book, Chris Berg and John Roskam explain what the Magna Carta is, where it came from, and why it matters.

The barons demanded of King John nothing less than a wholesale revolution of government. The Magna Carta establish the fundamental link between tax and consent.

Eight centuries later, understanding how our liberties came from a revolt against oppressive taxation has never been more important.

Available from the Institute of Public Affairs and Amazon.com

Submission to Treasury consultation into exposure draft of Tax Laws Amendment (Tax Integrity Multinational Anti-avoidance Law) Bill 2015

With Sinclair Davidson

Introduction: The Tax Laws Amendment (Tax Integrity Multinational Anti-avoidance Law) Bill 2015 exposure draft represents an important and concerning watershed in the practice of Australian corporate tax governance.

The draft bill would base the assessment of Australian tax liabilities on an assessment of tax rules in other countries. It undermines global tax agreements to which Australia is a part that have developed to prevent double taxation, risking the phenomenon that those agreements were designed to avoid. It offers a disincentive for the world’s biggest firms from establishing operations in Australia. It mischaracterises readily understandable business decisions as tax avoidance and penalises firms for normal corporate structural practices.

The scope of this legislation amounts to a substantial, yet entirely unpredictable, increase in corporate tax, and an attendant increase in the regulatory burden faced by large firms operating in Australia. We dispute the claim that this is a “tax integrity” measure. It is very much a tax increase.

Available in PDF here.

A Welcome Mutiny Against Protectionism

It’s sometimes thought that the economic disputes that characterised the 1970s and ’80s are finished. The debate over protectionism, for instance, has been displaced by more modern debates over inequality and the environment.

Two issues raised by the Government in the last week show how untrue that is.

On Wednesday, Warren Truss outlined the Government’s plan to deregulate Australia’s coastal shipping industry, and yesterday the Australian Financial Review reported the Government was considering opening up domestic air routes in the north to foreign airlines.

I was critical of the Government last week for being reform-shy, but these proposals are very, very good.

Both coastal shipping and airlines are governed by cabotage rights – a peculiar 19th century term that refers to the right to transport passengers and goods between two points within a single country.

The issue here is whether foreign-registered or owned or crewed ships and planes have cabotage rights. For instance, can British Airways fly domestic routes in Australia? Under Australian law, only in emergencies. Are Chinese registered vessels allowed to ship goods between Brisbane and Sydney? Under highly regulated conditions designed to dissuade them from doing so.

Australia’s cabotage restrictions are protectionism by another name. They are restrictions on what economic activity foreign firms can conduct in Australia. And, as with any protectionist policy that limits competitive pressure, they raise costs to consumers and hinder economic growth.

Let’s start with coastal shipping.

Over the last few decades, the number of Australian registered ships used in coastal shipping has been in a dramatic decline. In 1996 there were 75 Australian registered ships in the coastal trade. Truss told a conference last week that number was now just 15. This is mostly due to the heavy burden of Australian industrial relations laws that apply to maritime workers on Australian vessels.

In 2008 a parliamentary committee declared the industry was in “crisis” and “many in the Australian maritime industry (believe) Australia would benefit from a revived and expanded coastal shipping sector”. One of those voices, of course, was the Maritime Union of Australia, whose members were losing out from the decline of Australian coastal ships.

So in 2012 the Gillard government passed a large package of reforms to the shipping industry that dramatically increased restrictions on what foreign vessels and foreign-crewed vessels could do in Australian waters.

Anthony Albanese, then infrastructure minister, made plain the protectionist purpose of the reforms: “Australian vessels paying Australian wages and providing jobs to Australians will be given preference to carry Australian goods on the Australian coast.”

As the former Productivity Commission head, Gary Banks, pointed out at the time, the government admitted these reforms were “strictly inconsistent” with the principles of competition policy that have driven economic liberalisation for the last few decades.

It’s worth recalling that those competition policies were originally established by Paul Keating’s Labor government. Labor now is, of course, opposed to any deregulation. For once that old commentary canard about the modern Labor Party having “betrayed the Hawke-Keating legacy” actually holds true.

Like shipping, aviation has avoided the comprehensive liberalisations of the last few decades. Not many travellers pause to question why domestic air consists almost entirely of Qantas and Virgin. Australia is a rich country. Surely some foreign airlines might want a piece of the busy Melbourne-Sydney corridor?

The Government’s proposal to allow foreign airlines to fly domestic routes is limited to northern Australia. It’s being sold as a “develop the north” strategy. But these sort of region-specific liberalisations are usually meant to be experimental tests for nation-wide reform. If airline deregulation works in the north – if it provides better, cheaper services – then there will be little reason not to roll it out across the country.

Liberalisation is always accompanied by the bleatings of those whose privileges are being taken away. “Qantas and Virgin are fighting a rearguard action behind the scenes” against the proposal, one report said yesterday. More publicly, Albanese complains deregulation would be “unilateral economic disarmament”.

It’s true that granting cabotage rights to foreign airlines is very rare around the world. But so what? Australia used to be a leader in market-oriented reform. A northern experiment would be good to prove these fears are nonsense.

In a sense these proposed Abbott Government reforms feel like the calm before the storm. This is cabotage liberalisation by choice before cabotage liberalisation becomes a necessity.

We are on the brink of an unpredictable yet certain revolutionary change in transport technology. Just as autonomous cars will challenge regulatory frameworks that assume every car has a driver, autonomous ships and autonomous planes will completely change the regulatory – and political – dynamic of these industries.

It sounds all a bit cringingly futurist but the pilotless ships are already seen by Australian unions as a threat to cabotage protectionism. No labour costs means pilotless ships can travel slower, thereby using less fuel. This is good for cheap shipping and the environment.

Likewise, when pilotless commercial aircraft become accepted, the old alliance between air services unions and airlines that underpins Labor’s opposition to deregulation is going to break down.

When this technological revolution occurs, limits on foreign firms operating in Australia are going to look like the 20th century anachronisms that they are.

An analogue budget meets the digital world

Budgets are a matter of light and shade. You have to get the balance right. And so having spent the weekend talking about its wonderful childcare plans, yesterday the Government paraded Treasurer Joe Hockey in front of cameras toformally announce some of the budget’s so-called “tax integrity measures”.

Yes, tax integrity measures. Treasury’s spinners would have worked hard on that little catchphrase. Funny how measures to strengthen the integrity of a tax system always seem to deliver more tax to the government.

First, the Government plans to adjust anti-avoidance laws to crack down on multinationals shifting their profits to lower taxing jurisdictions. Second, the Government is going to introduce a Netflix tax – that is, try to impose the GST on digital downloads like books, music, videos and so on.

These two are linked, and in an important way that perhaps even Hockey does not realise. Analogue tax system, meet digital world.

Let’s start with profit shifting. I’ve tackled the claims that multinationals are evading taxation by shifting their profits across borders on The Drum before. Long story short: it’s a beat up. But the Government wants a budget that sounds fair and nothing sounds fairer than beating up on big companies. The corporate tax is a diffuse and confusing tax. It’s designed that way.

We are told Australian Taxation Officers have been “embedded” in 30 different multinational companies. We’re not told which companies. And at the press conference yesterday the treasurer didn’t want to tell us how much revenue the new anti-avoidance measures might raise. “It’s billions of dollars, obviously.”

This should be a red flag. It’s true that Treasury doesn’t have a good track record for estimating how much money new taxes will raise – recall the embarrassingly low take from the mining tax. But this looks less like prudence and more like a lack of confidence. Running a media or political campaign against corporate tax avoidance is easy. Trying to reverse engineer the tax accounting of the world’s biggest firms is hard.

The Government’s crackdown has a certain Sisyphean quality. In a world where much value is tied up in intangible intellectual property, it is borderline nonsensical for politicians to command that economic activity occurs in this jurisdiction or that jurisdiction.

It used to be the case that big firms had capital assets you could see and touch. Factories, vehicles, equipment, land. What mattered to firms were things like location, infrastructure, access to markets, the price and skills of the labour force and so on. But now the assets of the biggest firms can be placed anywhere in the world instantaneously. So they tend to be clustered in low tax jurisdictions with established and reliable legal systems. Like Ireland and Singapore.

What isn’t obvious is why this is a bad thing. Yes, higher tax countries like Australia would prefer that firms book their intellectual property here so Treasury could skim some cash off the top. But treating big firms to a publicity focused “crackdown” only harms what we should be trying to improve: the Australian investment environment. Firms should want to put their assets here. Implicitly, the Government’s profit shifting claims suggest they do not.

There is almost exactly the same issue with the Netflix tax. Once again, the Government is trying to shoehorn a national tax better suited for an analogue era into the age of digital globalisation.

“It is plainly unfair that a supplier of digital products into Australia is not charging the GST whilst someone locally has to charge the GST,” Hockey said at the press conference on Monday.

But why? The GST is a tax that the Australian government has chosen to place on Australian businesses. If there is an unfairness here it is an unfairness imposed by the government when it chose to introduce the GST. It is not “unfair” that other countries do not charge the Australian GST.

When we import goods from other countries – real or intangible – they are priced free of the burden of the many taxes and regulatory costs imposed by the Australian government. This does not make international trade unfair. In fact, all those institutional, regulatory and geographic differences between different trading partners are why international trade is so beneficial.

And – as with the profit shifting debate – the Government’s rhetoric is running far ahead of its capabilities. It is absolute fantasy that Hockey and the Australian Treasury will be able to impose our taxes on international digital goods providers in any meaningful way.

Yes, they might be able to convince a few of the big firms to play ball. But many already are playing ball. Apple, for instance, already charges GST. Those online firms with no Australian base and few Australian interests are unlikely to sign up to this new impost. What’s the Government going to do? Censor them?

It was reported last week that the Abbott Government has scotched many of the tax increases on the table in order to free itself to attack Bill Shorten for wanting to increase tax. That’s good, as far as it goes.

But it would be better if they opposed tax increases because they find increasing tax inherently objectionable.

Ultimately, the tax “integrity measures” announced yesterday have to be seen in the context of a Government that thinks the only viable way back to surplus is more revenue.

Is The Looming Internet Filter Justified? Not Yet

Is intellectual property “property”? Kinda. Sorta. Not really.

That question might seem a bit abstract, on par with how-many-angels-can-fit-on-the-head-of-a-pin. But it matters. Because how Parliament sees the fundamental nature of one form of intellectual property – copyright – is almost certainly going to determine whether we are subjected to a new internet filter.

A bill now before Parliament, the Copyright Amendment (Online Infringement) Bill 2015, would give courts power to require internet providers block access to foreign websites whose dominant purpose is to facilitate copyright infringement.

In practice this means that Time Warner, which owns the copyright to Game of Thrones, could go to a judge and demand Telstra or iiNet block access to the Pirate Bay.

There are lots of problems with this bill. Its language is absurdly vague and broad. What counts as “facilitating” copyright infringement? Maybe it would block sites that offer virtual private networks, perhaps – those VPNs that Malcolm Turnbull has been encouraging us all to use.

But these are legislative technicalities. More importantly, blocking websites is censorship. The bill is an internet filter, no matter how stridently the Abbott Government rejects the comparison.

Supporters of the bill argue that technicalities and censorship aside, the real issue is that property is being stolen, and the Government – whose job it is to protect property – needs to act. After all, private property is a human right as much as free speech is. (Check out Article 17 of the Universal Declaration of Human Rights.)

It is true that intellectual property shares some of the characteristics of property. Like tangible property, intellectual property can be owned. It can be traded. So it’s property in those senses.

But, unlike tangible property, the use of intellectual property is not exclusive. When one person listens to a song or watches a movie they do not prevent others from doing so. It can’t be “stolen” in anything but a metaphorical sense.

This is why the law hasn’t treated intellectual property like real property. We don’t have a moral right to perpetual ownership and unimpeded exclusive control over the songs we write or movies we produce. For instance, copyright lasts 70 years after the death of the creator. Real property has no such time limits.

The scholar Tom W. Bell says that intellectual property would be better called intellectual privilege. This privilege is conferred for a specific purpose – to provide an incentive for the creation of new works. The theory is if we don’t confer that privilege people will supply less creative work than is socially desirable.

But that privilege has costs. For instance, copyright also stops us from using our other, real property as we see fit – we can’t use our computers, printing presses or internet connections as we would like. And we can’t build on the cultural capital created by others.

Thus the Howard government’s Ergas Report into Intellectual Property and Competition Policyargued that “over-compensating rights owners is as harmful, and perhaps even more harmful, than under-compensating them”.

So will the proposed Copyright Amendment (Online Infringement) Bill 2015 inspire the creation of new works? Even if placing a block on the Pirate Bay successfully stops internet piracy (please bear with me on this fantastic hypothetical) will artists go out and create more art as a result? And would enough new work be created to compensate for the restriction on free speech?

Many economists theorise about an “optimal” level of copyright protection – a sweet spot of enforcement and rules where the benefits of copyright are maximised and the costs are minimised.

Yet it is very hard to figure out where that sweet spot is. Even impossible. And the political system isn’t looking for the optimal policy – it’s looking for the most politically palatable policy, the one where the benefits are being maximised for politicians, not consumers.

In the United States, every time Mickey Mouse threatens to fall into the public domain the Walt Disney Company lobbies hard to extend copyright term limits. Nobody really thinks that maintaining Disney’s exclusive rights over Mickey for another decade or two will lead to more creative works being produced. But these are decisions made by politicians, not blackboard economists, so the extensions get granted.

The Australian Parliament has been considering copyright enforcement changes since last year. We’ve heard a lot of pontificating about “theft” and digital access and global release dates.

But the only policy question is whether website blocking would inspire the creation of enough new content to make up for the fact that the Government is censoring the internet.

And, so far, nobody has shown that would be the case.

Liberty, Equality & Democracy

Connor Court Publishing, 2015

No one has the right to rule. If we don’t believe our fellow citizens are intellectually capable of deciding what and how much to eat, whether to drink, or how to arrange their financial affairs, then why do we think they are capable of voting?’

We live in a fundamentally undemocratic age. Governments treat their citizens as incapable of making decisions for themselves. Policy-making power has been taken out of the hands of elected politicians. Poll after poll shows the public are unhappy with democracy itself. In this wide-ranging book, Chris Berg makes the case for radical democratic equality, and a democracy order that truly respects the equality and rights of its citizens.

Available from Connor Court Publishing and Amazon.com

Opening statement to Commonwealth Legal and Constitutional Affairs Legislation Committee inquiry into the Copyright Amendment (Online Infringement) Bill 2015

Copyright is a limited quasi-monopoly privilege granted by the state to authors of creative works for a specific and utilitarian purpose, which is to encourage the development of new creative works. This, in my view, is the proper frame in which to consider any changes to copyright law or any new mechanisms to control copyright infringement such as are proposed in the Copyright Amendment (Online Infringement) Bill. To what extent will changes in the law encourage or discourage the creation of new works?

Parliament has a complicated balancing act to perform. Copyright, after all, is not socially costless. It constrains what we might be able to do otherwise with our own property. It prevents us from exercising rights to how we might use our printing presses, musical and television equipment, computers or internet connections. This is not at all to say that the copyright privilege is unjustified or unjustifiable—far from it—but that the utilitarian calculation that society needs to make when considering copyright is whether the benefits of any marginal changes to these privileges outweigh the costs to more fundamental rights like freedom of expression and the right for individuals to use their property and possessions as they see fit. This is why the Howard government’s 2000 Ergas report into intellectual property argued:

Over-compensating rights owners is as harmful, and perhaps even more harmful, than under-compensating them.

Quite apart from any freedom of expression concerns with the copyright bill before parliament, it is not at all clear to me that the social benefits conferred by this new censorship power to block access to websites outweigh the social costs. The Institute of Public Affairs has an in-principle objection to internet censorship on free speech grounds, which I think by now most people will be familiar with, but there is a specific issue I want to raise in the context of this bill.

The bill dramatically lowers the bar for which internet censorship is being proposed. After all, while the previous government’s internet filter proposed to block websites that were hosting violent pornography, child abuse material and so forth, the bill before parliament today proposes censorship on the basis that some websites host copyrighted content. The two censorship proposals are hardly the same scale and, in the case of copyright infringement, we are actually talking about a civil rather than a criminal wrong. The language in the bill is excessively vague. Other submissions have pointed to the undefined and broad consequences, for instance, of the word ‘facilitate’ and warned of possible judicial creep. But I would like to make a final observation.

Parliament, and the political process, is not a venue well-designed to calculate dispassionately the most efficient level of copyright privileges and the most efficient changes to enforcement mechanisms. This is a well-known collective choice issue. It may be possible to draw blackboard diagrams that determine the ultimate copyright rules and level of enforcement. However, unfortunately, policymakers lack the necessary information to do so. Copyright law therefore suffers from what Friedrich Hayek famously called the ‘knowledge problem’. That problem, in our view, presents a strong presumption against further increases in the copyright enforcement powers and an absolute presumption against internet censorship for copyright purposes.

Classical Liberalism in Australian Economics

Abstract: Classical liberalism, the tradition of free markets and individual liberty, has an outsider status in the Australian economics profession. This paper surveys the origin of Australian classical liberal economics in the nineteenth century, its sharp decline in the first half of the twentieth century, and its revival and growth in recent decades. Despite a period of successful market-oriented economic reform in the 1980s and 1990s, surveys suggest that classical liberalism is a minority viewpoint among Australian economists. The classical liberal tradition is sustained only by a small number of institutions and individuals. To the extent that it is influential, it is influential thanks to a political culture that prioritises public engagement. Classical liberal economists have a high degree of participation in political and economic debate outside the academy.

Author(s): Chris Berg

Journal: Econ Journal Watch

Vol: 12 Issue: 2 Year: 2015

DOI: https://econjwatch.org/articles/classical-liberalism-in-australian-economics

Cite: Berg, Chris. “Classical Liberalism in Australian Economics.” Econ Journal Watch, vol. 12, no. 2, May 2015, pp. 192–220.

Continue reading “Classical Liberalism in Australian Economics”

The Undone Tasks of Deregulation

Back in 2007, Kevin Rudd thought he could make a big political statement by outflanking John Howard as a free marketeer. He claimed to be the true “economic conservative”, and attacked the Howard government’s “reckless spending”. But that was just half of Rudd’s pitch. A headline in the Australian Financial Review in October that year screamed, “Labor blasts PM over red tape burden”. Readers learned that Rudd had “savaged” the Coalition for the regulation that was “strangling” business. “Stand by for the Regulation Revolution,” said theSydney Morning Herald; “cutting back the maze of business regulation and red tape” would be one of Rudd’s “top policy priorities”.

They say the past is another country. Campaigns are another planet. Once handed power by the Australian voters, the practice of the Rudd government was light years away from its soaring campaign rhetoric. Yes, true to Rudd’s promise, Lindsay Tanner was appointed Australia’s Minister for Finance and Deregulation. Yet one of Tanner’s first acts as minister was to preside over a vast increase in regulatory control over the finance sector, adopting new federal anti-money-laundering and counter-terrorism-financing laws that had been prepared by the Howard government.

This was just a taste of things to come. Tanner was our first deregulation minister and the experiment was a failure. Just as he was unable, as Minister for Finance, to prevent the massive splurge of government spending instigated by Rudd, Wayne Swan and Treasury Secretary Ken Henry, he was unable to hold back the tidal wave of new regulation that came with an interventionist government. By the twilight of the Labor government, this wave of regulatory interventionism had become a flood. Rudd’s professed disdain for the red tape burden strangling business was forgotten. Vast new regulatory frameworks were being imposed on labour markets, financial markets, employment conditions, child care, hospitals and health, aged care, competition law, health and safety laws, higher education, charities, coastal shipping, and of course the environment.

These increased the regulatory burden on individual sectors, but also the economy in general. For instance, the cost of regulation imposed on the mining and energy sectors flow through to raise the costs of downstream products. Just as taxes—like the carbon and mining taxes—reduce economic growth and living standards, so can regulation imposed on these vital sectors.

Some of the most egregious new regulations were not successfully implemented. Communications Minister Stephen Conroy was unable to pass his large-scale attempt to regulate fairness in the press. Attorney-General Nicola Roxon was unable to pass her attempt to create a right not to be offended on everything from race to politics in the workplace. Roxon did however manage to pass that manifestly absurd and deeply symbolic instance of regulatory over-reach—plain packaging on tobacco products.

These new regulations became a source of pride for the Labor government. Trying to combat the sense that parliament under Julia Gillard’s minority government was chaotic, Anthony Albanese used to brag about just how many pages of legislation Gillard had ushered through parliament. As the months ticked by the number grew ever larger. In six years, Labor passed a whopping 975 acts, adding up to 38,874 pages of legislation.

It’s true that the volume of legislation is an imperfect measure of the growth in regulation, for a number of important reasons. It is indicative rather than demonstrative. It does not take into account the effect that each new piece of legislation will have, nor does it take into account the fact that some legislation might repeal existing law, thereby reducing the regulatory burden. On the other side of the ledger these figures do not include subordinate legislation nor any state laws and council bylaws. But it is extremely suggestive. And constant legislative change imposes its own costs, as we shall discuss below. In 2012 the Institute of Public Affairs calculated that there were 103,908 pages of Commonwealth legislation on the books.

Rudd’s deregulation push may have been brazen, but every government comes to power promising to cut red tape. The Howard government had its own promise to reduce the regulation which was “enveloping small business” but the fruits of that labour are hard to see. Australia was more regulated after the Howard years rather than less, as I pointed out in the 2009 book The Howard Era. For all the stability and good governance that the Coalition offered between 1996 and 2007 it did little to stem the growing tide of regulation. Rudd wasn’t wrong when he diagnosed the red tape problem in 2007. It’s just that he wasn’t the person—and his party wasn’t game—to fix it.

So how does the Abbott government shape up? There are positive early signs. On the headline figure of legislative activity, 2014 was a good year. There were just 135 acts constituting 4607 pages of legislation passed through the Commonwealth parliament last year. This is a drop from the more than 5000 pages passed in 2013, and happily well below the 8150 passed in 2012. No doubt this is in part due to the trouble that the government has had passing its bills through a hostile, unpredictable Senate. But it is also due to the efforts of the Coalition’s own deregulation minister, Josh Frydenberg, and the emphasis that the Abbott government has placed on its deregulation agenda. Abbott and Frydenberg made deregulation one of the central features of its economic message in the Gillard years, leaning heavily on reducing the regulatory burden as part of its plan to revive the economy after years of sluggishness.

And yet. While the Abbott government repealed 57,000 pages of legislation in 2014—and claims to have saved the economy a whopping $2.1 billion a year—much of that which was repealed was already defunct. The real work of deregulation, if it is to occur, hasn’t started.

Indeed, the Abbott government’s deregulation experience shows why this agenda is so hard to pursue. In 2013, the much-publicised “Repeal Days”—a single parliamentary day every six months dedicated solely to repealing law rather than introducing it—were important but, as they came around, their agenda items kept disappearing. For instance, the proposal to eliminate the entirely unnecessary gender-equality reporting requirements imposed on businesses with more than 100 employees had to be dropped, apparently for political reasons. The reforms to the Labor government’s Future of Financial Advice program, which would have taken the edge off some of the most extreme regulatory controls but nevertheless left the previous government’s regulatory framework largely in place, were implemented by regulation. In a surprise upset the Future of Financial Advice reforms were reversed by the Senate at the end of the year. Other deregulatory proposals—such as the deregulation of higher education—have floundered as well.

Every regulation, even the most absurd, has a unique justification, and its own constituency. Gender-equality reporting is “not an issue of red tape”, according to Claire Braund, the head of an organisation called Women on Boards Australia. But it is the epitome of red tape—it imposes no other compliance requirements on firms except paperwork, and paperwork that has no other purpose except informing government. It should be the low-hanging fruit of regulatory reduction. There is not a single person in the country, except perhaps the bureaucrats that administer the program, who would be materially worse off if this requirement was abandoned. Yet gender reporting could not be repealed.

In some areas the government seems intent on going backwards. The Abbott government started 2015 with a stalled budget and by talking up a range of regulatory increases. It’s clamping down on foreign ownership in property. It’s introducing new country-of-origin labels to food products. It’s talking about lowering the GST threshold on imports and digital products, which would require enormous new regulatory infrastructure for retailers and importers alike. It has passed legislation to impose new controls on social media websites to clamp down on cyberbullying and to require internet service providers to keep vast amounts of information on every Australian’s online activities just in case they are in the future suspected of a crime or regulatory violation.

We can bat the pros and cons of these proposals around. They ought to be debated earnestly. But they illustrate that even a government as apparently dedicated to deregulation as the Coalition under Tony Abbott is nevertheless unable to resist the steady creep of new economic controls. There’s something much deeper going on here than traditional party ideology. While it is clear that Labor’s approach to regulation was worse than what we saw under the Howard government and what we have seen so far under Abbott, we’re talking about differences in degree, not kind. There is a deep and seemingly inexorable logic of modern democratic government that pushes it towards regulatory excess. Recognising we have a problem is the first step to solving it.

And it is a problem. Each year the World Econ­omic Forum publishes a Global Competitiveness Report which rates world economies according to a large range of indicators that would help facilitate business. Australia does relatively well overall. We rate well on things like education, the soundness of our banks, the health of our population, the depth of our financial markets, the professionalism of management and so on. But we are catastrophically bad when it comes to “burden of government regulation”—a terrible 124th in the world, sharing a spot with such economic powerhouses as Iran, Spain and Zimbabwe. Our competitors rate much higher. The United States is at eighty-second, while Canada is twenty-ninth.

The Australian Industry Group surveyed 241 CEOs in Australian businesses. The number of executives who nominated government regulation as one of their top three impediments to growth has grown from 9 per cent in 2011 to 11 per cent in 2014. This figure may seem relatively small in isolation, but given that it competes against other factors like the global economic and investment climate, it is strikingly high. Fully 83 per cent of CEOs believe they face a medium to high level of regulatory burden—particularly in the areas of industrial relations and health and safety.

The Minerals Council of Australia commissioned a review of legislative controls on the mining industry. It found that the number of primary pieces of legislation overseeing project approvals nation-wide increased from ninety-four to 144 between 2006 and 2013. Subordinate legislation increased even more: from sixty-six in 2006 to 119 in 2013. As they told the Productivity Commission’s 2013 review into mineral and energy resource exploration, the largest mining states, Western Australia and Queensland, have some of the most onerous regulatory burdens. Hancock Prospecting’s Roy Hill iron ore project in the Pilbara has required a staggering 4000 licences, approvals and permits—much of them imposed by the state government.

The cost burden of regulation is well known. But more important—and harder to test—is how regulations shape and constrain the economy itself. A modern economy is subject to constant shocks. Technologies change. Preferences change. New business models supplant old business models. Political events in distant countries can have unpredictable ricochet effects for Australian firms. Foreign price changes suddenly render existing ways of work unprofitable, or open up new opportunities. Firms have to constantly shift their operations, their ways of doing things, even their entire business models sometimes just to stay afloat. Economic change does not just occur in boom-bust cycles, nor in the long-term technological revolutions that have characterised the last two centuries. Tiny changes to supply lines, seemingly minor legislative changes in distant countries, and modest but constant adjustments to consumer goods mean that the economic ground is constantly shifting under the feet of the business sector.

Contrast this unstable economic dynamism with the political system that proposes to regulate it. Statutes reflect the nature of the world only at the moment of their passage through parliament. Legislation is static—black words in leather books that can only be altered through fraught and complex political negotiation. Even minor, uncontroversial legislative amendments can take months. Serious change can take years, from green papers to white papers to exposure drafts to committee inquiries to law of the land. Each of those legislative changes that the Gillard government was so pleased to have overseen was a long time in the making—the fruit of months and years of bureaucratic busywork. As a consequence the economic environment depicted in statute is almost always long out of date. Embedded in each statute are assumptions—about the shape of industry, technological ability, the force of competition—which do not last.

In other words, no matter how active the government is, the law is a static instrument. The economy it governs is dynamic. This creates serious problems. As rock beats scissors, law trumps business needs. Firms facing economic headwinds find that their ability to adjust is limited by the legislative environment they operate in: legal constraints are constraints on business flexibility. In an Institute of Public Affairs paper published in December 2014, Dom Talimanidis demonstrated the perilous decline in entrepreneurism in Australia. Where new businesses constituted 17 per cent of total businesses in 2003-04, in 2012-13 new businesses were just 11 per cent of total businesses. Unsurprisingly, the relative decline in business entry is greatest in those states that are the least economically free.

The burden of regulation is most obvious when we look at individual firms—the time spent on paperwork, the business opportunities not pursued. But all these little disincentives and distractions add up. Regulatory excess can have serious macro-economic consequences. In an important paper published by the Swedish think-tank Research Institute of Industrial Economics in January 2015, the economist Christian Bjørnskov looked at the relationship between standard measures of economic freedom and economic crises. As Bjørnskov finds, a high degree of economic freedom does little to prevent countries from suffering an economic crisis. But the degree to which an economy is free is a very important factor in how quickly a country recovers from a crisis. The things that matter here are not whether taxes are low, government spending is modest, or whether the rule of law is strong, but how efficient the regulatory environment is.

Economic crises necessitate a large-scale reallocation of resources, away from troubled sectors and into more stable ones. At the individual level, a person who has lost a job in an economic crisis needs to move rapidly into new employment—perhaps even new employment in a new industry—before the harm of unemployment becomes too manifest. Regulations like occupational licensing and industrial relations laws that raise the cost of employment act as a handbrake on the necessary economic adjustment. All regulation in some way prevents resources from being used alternatively—even if it is just the opportunity cost of time spent filling out gender-reporting forms. Even when regulation is desirable, we have to recognise that all regulation makes for a less flexible economy, and one less able to adapt to change.

One possible answer to the problem of legislative immobility is for parliament to grant a certain amount of discretion to adjust and interpret regulations according to changing circumstances. This is what we do when we hand decision-making power over to regulatory agencies. Yet vesting unelected regulators with discretionary power does more harm than good. It exacerbates regulatory uncertainty, with serious consequences for the private plans of individuals and firms. It facilitates regulatory “capture”. And of course it has a democratic legitimacy problem—under whose authority do regulators make what are effectively public-policy decisions?

Nevertheless, policy-makers today lean heavily on delegation to regulatory agencies, handing them quasi-legislative power. In an important book, Is Administrative Law Unlawful? (2014), the Columbia Law School professor Philip Hamburger traces the origins of such delegated legislative power back past the creation of regulatory agencies at the beginning of the twentieth century—where most scholars’ history stops—all the way to the pronouncements of medieval kings. Hamburger draws a distinction between administrative pronouncements by executive governments that are intended to bind officers of the executive and those that are intended to bind society more generally. The former form of pronouncement is obviously necessary for government to function. Bosses need some way of instructing their employees. But pronouncements that affect the public more generally ought to be the purview of the legislature, not the executive. These are more akin to the exercise of the royal prerogative than democratic law.

We often imagine that our modern concerns are distinct from those of the past. But how much legislative power the executive could exercise without parliamentary approval was one of the great contests in the lead-up to the English Civil War. The seventeenth-century English historian Roger Twysden declared that “the basis or ground of all the liberty and franchise of the subject” was “this maxim, that the king cannot alone alter the law”. Yet through executive pronouncement and delegation governments have vested vast legislative power in what scholars call “non-majoritarian” regulatory and bureaucratic agencies.

We are yet to work out the long-term democratic significance of this approach to governance. But the economic consequences are dire. Friedrich Hayek argued that the rule of law had three requirements. Laws had to be general, that is, they applied not to specific circumstances and individuals but to society as a whole. They had to be equal—they had to apply to all people in society equally, without discrimination. And finally they had to be certain. Certainty is a strange word to be used in connection with economic life, of course: there is nothing certain about the future. But the challenge of economic uncertainty is exacerbated by political uncertainty. Hayek wrote:

I doubt whether the significance which the certainty of the law has for the smooth and efficient working of economic life can be exaggerated, and there is probably no single factor which has contributed more to the greater prosperity of the Western World, compared with the Orient, than the relative certainty of the law which in the West had early been achieved.

So laws ought to be clearly spelled out. They need to be “known”. Their consequences and significance ought to be discernible to all those who are expected to follow them. We ought to limit the discretion that administrators and bureaucrats have in applying the law.

But does this black-letter approach to law really create certainty? What is certain about black-letter law that is subject to constant revision? Or black-letter law that is constantly being supplemented, complemented and expanded? The volume of legislation currently being pushed through parliaments, state and Commonwealth, Labor or Coalition, and invented by regulatory agencies, is itself a challenge to the certainty of the law. As Bruno Leoni wrote in his classic study Freedom and the Law:

The more intense and accelerated is the process of law-making, the more uncertain will it be that present legislation will last for any length of time. Moreover, there is nothing to prevent a law, certain in the above-mentioned sense, from being unpredictably changed by another law no less “certain” than the previous one.

Thus, the certainty of the law, in this sense, could be called the short-run certainty of the law.

For anybody who had a time horizon longer than that short run, the law was anything but certain. Leoni’s book was published in 1961. His lifetime (Leoni was born in 1913) had seen enormous economic and technological change, but the scale of those changes pales in comparison to the shifts in technology and business that we are seeing today. In just a few years entire industries have shifted out of the terrestrial world into online. Ubiquitous communications have made older traditions of work obsolete. It is absurd that we have shop trading-hour regulations, as still exist in Western Australia, co-existing alongside always-on mobile internet shopping. While firms like Uber and Airbnb are revolutionising transport and accommodation respectively, they present a competitive threat to the taxi and hotel industries that have been lumbered with long-standing and costly regulation. Stretching our view slightly further into the future, today’s regulatory assumptions are going to be challenged by new technologies like 3D printers, consumer drones and digital cryptocurrencies like Bitcoin. No matter how manic is the legislative activity that characterises our political system, it is nevertheless unable to keep up with social and technological change.

Despite the small but important successes of the Abbott government in reducing some regulation and clearing the statute books of anachronisms, it is obvious that the deregulation movement has stalled. Deregulation is now more a political slogan than a serious public-policy project. Politicians have ceased trying to justify the purposes of deregulation and now treat deregulation as a good in-and-of-itself. This is a testament to the intellectual success of the deregulators of the past—who made the case for lower regulation a virtual self-evident proposition—but it has left the political class with little appetite to actually argue the case for needed reform. When each side has committed itself to deregulation, all that remains is a rule-in, rule-out game. Unfortunately, in the nature of politics, rule-outs are more common than rule-ins. The populist pressure for new law is far greater than the intellectual pressure for less.

Thus the deregulation stalemate, a stalemate more pernicious as we move towards an unpredictable economic future and hyper-innovations in technology. The issue is not how many “repeal days” are scheduled in a year. The issue is how the government sees its relationship with the economy. We do not lack alternatives to the over-regulation path we have taken. Leoni was an advocate of the common law—the system of private, particular and iterative law-making vastly superior to the statutory law which now dominates our legal systems. Rather than expecting politicians to play constant catch-up with economic and technological changes, the common law would allow legal issues to be solved when they arise. Law can be discovered, rather than imposed.

Hayek spoke of “generality” as an ideal of the rule of law. In modern regulatory parlance this is akin to “neutrality”. Four decades ago the Fraser government’s Campbell Committee into financial regulation spoke of “competitive neutrality”, just as the Rudd government’s Convergence Review into media and communications regulation spoke of “technological neutrality”. The idea is that products or services that compete with each other should face the same regulatory burden. Deposits in building societies should be regulated the same way as those in banks. Video broadcast over television channels should be regulated the same way as video served over the internet.

Neutrality has proven to be more of a catchphrase than a policy program. This is because genuine regulatory neutrality undermines some of the most fundamental assumptions of government economic management. To regulate is to control. Every advocate of new regulation has an idea of the world that their proposal would create. Regulation is always purposeful—it has a goal, a vision of a fixed future. For all the valuable discussion of technological neutrality, Labor’s Convergence Review collapsed into absurdity when it was unable to shed a fundamental belief in the ability of governments and regulators to shape the world around them. Rather than reducing the burden on highly regulated television services, it proposed to expand those regulations onto the ungovernable internet. Neutral, yes. But also absurd.

The Convergence Review offers a microcosm of the broader regulation problem. Regulatory excess is the result of governments trying to impose their values on the economy—using law to shape the economy according to their own preferences rather than allowing the economy to flow unpredictably according to consumer demand and entrepreneurial experimentation. In that sense, it is a reflection of the political system from which it emanates. If the Abbott government wants to go down in Australian history as a significant reform-driven government, then the “deregulation agenda” is not enough. It needs to start a serious rethink of the relationship between the dynamic, entrepreneurial economy and the static but over-energetic regulatory state.